Jump to content

Is immigration good for the economy?

From The Wikle
WikleBot (talk | contribs)
m Updated page with AI-generated answer [automated edit by WikleBot]
 
Line 1: Line 1:
''Written by AI. Help improve this answer by adding to the sources section. When the sources section is updated this article will regenerate.''
''Written by AI. Help improve this answer by adding to the sources section. When the sources section is updated this article will regenerate.''


Immigration and the economy
Immigration and the economy
Across studies and political contexts, researchers generally agree that immigration has both measurable benefits and measurable costs for host economies. The size and distribution of each depend on the migrants’ age structure, skills, legal status, and the host country’s labour-market and welfare institutions.


# Short-run labour-market effects  
Aggregate growth 
  • Newcomers usually earn less than comparable native workers during their first years in the host country, but wage gaps narrow markedly within a generation as language proficiency, credentials recognition and social networks improve [1].   
* A steady inflow of working-age migrants expands the labour force and can help slow population aging, thereby supporting GDP growth [1][2].  
  • Large empirical exercises for the EU find only “minor and often statistically insignificant” impacts—positive or negative—on the wages of incumbent workers in the short run; the main variable is whether immigrants obtain work quickly and at skill levels that match their education [2].
* In the European Union, modelling by economists for the European Commission projects that keeping net migration close to present levels would raise the bloc’s average growth rate by around 0.2–0.3 pp per year over the next two decades, largely because migrants are younger than natives and have higher employment rates than is often assumed [2].   
* Historical evidence from the United States shows that the average immigrant household catches up to natives in income and tax contributions within one generation, contributing to productivity growth through entrepreneurship and occupational mobility [1].


# Growth, productivity and entrepreneurship  
Fiscal impact  
  • Historical data for the United States show that immigrant participation was central to industrial expansion in the late-19th and early-20th centuries, supplying both labour for factories and founders for new firms; similar patterns are visible today in high-growth sectors such as technology and health services [1].   
* The net fiscal balance (taxes paid minus transfers received) is usually positive for recently arrived, prime-age workers but can turn negative when large shares of newcomers are dependants or reach retirement age [2].   
  • In the EU, model projections to 2060 show that higher migration rates raise aggregate output by expanding the working-age population and slowing workforce ageing; the positive effect varies from 0.5 % to 2 % of GDP depending on the skills mix and labour-market integration speed [2].
* EU simulations find that if newcomers resemble the current migrant stock the average lifetime fiscal contribution is slightly positive; under a “low-integration” scenario, the same cohort would create a small deficit, suggesting that labour-market integration is the decisive variable rather than sheer numbers [2]. 
* Refugee intakes can be an exception. A case study on the hypothetical resettlement of hundreds of thousands of Palestinian refugees in high-income countries estimates a per-capita fiscal cost of roughly €16,000 in the first five years, driven by housing, language training, and welfare outlays [3]. The author argues that these costs would outweigh near-term growth benefits unless complemented by fast-track work-permit policies [3].


# Fiscal balance  
Distributional effects  
  • Because immigrants arrive disproportionately in their prime working years, they pay taxes sooner and draw on pensions later, producing a “demographic dividend” that partially offsets the fiscal pressures of population ageing [2].   
* Low-skilled natives in directly competing occupations can experience downward wage pressure, while complementary workers and capital owners benefit from lower production costs [1].   
  • Simulations for the EU27 suggest that, under baseline integration assumptions, the average net fiscal contribution of a recent migrant cohort remains positive for two decades and turns slightly negative only as the cohort reaches retirement; in an optimistic scenario of rapid labour-market convergence the net contribution stays positive throughout the projection horizon [2]. 
* Regions with flexible labour markets and portable welfare benefits see quicker convergence in employment rates between immigrants and natives, narrowing distributional tensions [2].
  • The same studies warn that slow integration or very low participation rates can wipe out the dividend, producing small but persistent deficits in countries with rigid labour markets [2].


# Assimilation and long-run convergence  
Points of controversy 
  • Cultural and economic assimilation generally occurs faster than public perception allows: after roughly thirty years, rates of English use at home, inter-marriage, income and educational attainment among U.S. immigrants’ children approach or surpass native averages [1].   
* Optimistic assessments highlight the long-run growth payoff and the historically demonstrated capacity of migrants to assimilate economically [1].  
  • Successful assimilation reinforces economic gains by boosting mobility and entrepreneurship; conversely, segregation or legal barriers that keep migrants in low-productivity jobs limit overall benefits [1][2].
* Sceptical accounts focus on short-run fiscal burdens when large humanitarian inflows arrive faster than housing and job-matching systems can adjust [3].   
* All sources agree that policy choices—language training, credential recognition, welfare conditionality—are pivotal in turning potential net costs into net gains [2][3].


# Points of agreement and disagreement in the literature 
Timeline of public discourse (selected milestones) 
  • Both sources concur that immigration is not automatically good or bad for the economy; outcomes hinge on policy choices that affect speed of labour-market entry, skills recognition and language acquisition [1][2].   
* 1990s: OECD labour-market papers begin quantifying small but positive GDP effects from post-Cold-War migration; debate largely academic. 
  • The U.S.-centred analysis stresses long-run dynamism and inter-generational mobility [1], whereas the EU fiscal study highlights short- to medium-term budgetary effects and scenarios in which poor integration generates modest costs [2].   
* 2005–2015: EU enlargements and the 2015 refugee crisis shift the spotlight to fiscal impacts; several governments commission dynamic-simulation studies, culminating in the Commission’s 2018 “net fiscal impact” projections [2].   
  • No direct contradiction exists between the two; rather, they frame the same mechanisms—age structure, skills and assimilation—at different time horizons.
* 2016–2020: US presidential campaigns revive the assimilation debate; think-tank studies stress the inter-generational economic mobility of immigrants [1]
* 2023: Conflicts in the Middle East rekindle discussion on large-scale refugee resettlement. Cost estimates for absorbing Palestinian refugees circulate widely online, fuelling scepticism about fiscal capacity in high-debt economies [3].   
* 2024-present: Policymakers weigh sector-specific labour shortages against housing constraints; emphasis shifts from “how many” migrants to “how productive” their integration can be.


Timeline of public discourse
Conclusion  
 
When migrants are quickly integrated into the labour market, immigration is usually a net economic positive. Where integration lags or intake is dominated by dependants, short-to-medium-term fiscal deficits can emerge. The divergence in findings among the cited authors reflects differing assumptions about integration speed rather than disagreement over the underlying mechanisms.
1880-1924  • “New immigration” from Southern and Eastern Europe fuels U.S. industrial boom and sparks first large-scale economic worries about wage competition.  
1965-1986  • Post-1965 immigration wave and studies of wage impacts launch modern debate; early econometric work finds small negative effects for low-skilled natives, slight gains for others. 
1990s-2000s • Growing empirical consensus in the U.S. that aggregate gains outweigh distributional costs; EU discussion remains limited owing to lower migration levels. 
2015        • Refugee inflows during the Syrian crisis push immigration to the top of the EU policy agenda; questions arise over fiscal sustainability. 
2018        • Publication of “Projecting the net fiscal impact of immigration in the EU” provides first union-wide long-horizon estimates, showing mostly positive effects under realistic assumptions [2].
2023        • “The Assimilation Myth” article argues that U.S. immigrants still assimilate rapidly and that fears of perpetual cultural or economic separation are unfounded [1].
 
Conclusion
 
Across both American historical data and forward-looking EU fiscal models, the balance of evidence shows that immigration tends to be economically beneficial when newcomers integrate into the labour market within a reasonable time frame and when host-country policies facilitate skill use and language acquisition. The gains are not automatic; they depend on policy design, market flexibility and the demographic profile of arrivals.


== Sources ==
== Sources ==

Latest revision as of 00:15, 29 April 2025

Written by AI. Help improve this answer by adding to the sources section. When the sources section is updated this article will regenerate.

Immigration and the economy Across studies and political contexts, researchers generally agree that immigration has both measurable benefits and measurable costs for host economies. The size and distribution of each depend on the migrants’ age structure, skills, legal status, and the host country’s labour-market and welfare institutions.

Aggregate growth

  • A steady inflow of working-age migrants expands the labour force and can help slow population aging, thereby supporting GDP growth [1][2].
  • In the European Union, modelling by economists for the European Commission projects that keeping net migration close to present levels would raise the bloc’s average growth rate by around 0.2–0.3 pp per year over the next two decades, largely because migrants are younger than natives and have higher employment rates than is often assumed [2].
  • Historical evidence from the United States shows that the average immigrant household catches up to natives in income and tax contributions within one generation, contributing to productivity growth through entrepreneurship and occupational mobility [1].

Fiscal impact

  • The net fiscal balance (taxes paid minus transfers received) is usually positive for recently arrived, prime-age workers but can turn negative when large shares of newcomers are dependants or reach retirement age [2].
  • EU simulations find that if newcomers resemble the current migrant stock the average lifetime fiscal contribution is slightly positive; under a “low-integration” scenario, the same cohort would create a small deficit, suggesting that labour-market integration is the decisive variable rather than sheer numbers [2].
  • Refugee intakes can be an exception. A case study on the hypothetical resettlement of hundreds of thousands of Palestinian refugees in high-income countries estimates a per-capita fiscal cost of roughly €16,000 in the first five years, driven by housing, language training, and welfare outlays [3]. The author argues that these costs would outweigh near-term growth benefits unless complemented by fast-track work-permit policies [3].

Distributional effects

  • Low-skilled natives in directly competing occupations can experience downward wage pressure, while complementary workers and capital owners benefit from lower production costs [1].
  • Regions with flexible labour markets and portable welfare benefits see quicker convergence in employment rates between immigrants and natives, narrowing distributional tensions [2].

Points of controversy

  • Optimistic assessments highlight the long-run growth payoff and the historically demonstrated capacity of migrants to assimilate economically [1].
  • Sceptical accounts focus on short-run fiscal burdens when large humanitarian inflows arrive faster than housing and job-matching systems can adjust [3].
  • All sources agree that policy choices—language training, credential recognition, welfare conditionality—are pivotal in turning potential net costs into net gains [2][3].

Timeline of public discourse (selected milestones)

  • 1990s: OECD labour-market papers begin quantifying small but positive GDP effects from post-Cold-War migration; debate largely academic.
  • 2005–2015: EU enlargements and the 2015 refugee crisis shift the spotlight to fiscal impacts; several governments commission dynamic-simulation studies, culminating in the Commission’s 2018 “net fiscal impact” projections [2].
  • 2016–2020: US presidential campaigns revive the assimilation debate; think-tank studies stress the inter-generational economic mobility of immigrants [1].
  • 2023: Conflicts in the Middle East rekindle discussion on large-scale refugee resettlement. Cost estimates for absorbing Palestinian refugees circulate widely online, fuelling scepticism about fiscal capacity in high-debt economies [3].
  • 2024-present: Policymakers weigh sector-specific labour shortages against housing constraints; emphasis shifts from “how many” migrants to “how productive” their integration can be.

Conclusion When migrants are quickly integrated into the labour market, immigration is usually a net economic positive. Where integration lags or intake is dominated by dependants, short-to-medium-term fiscal deficits can emerge. The divergence in findings among the cited authors reflects differing assumptions about integration speed rather than disagreement over the underlying mechanisms.

Sources[edit]

  1. https://inquisitivebird.xyz/p/the-assimilation-myth-america
  2. https://migrant-integration.ec.europa.eu/library-document/projecting-net-fiscal-impact-immigration-eu_en
  3. https://www.lorenzofromoz.net/p/taking-in-palestinian-refugees-is

Question[edit]

Is immigration good for the economy?